The Urban Exodus and How Greatness Goes Bankrupt
September 30, 2020
The best-case scenario is those who love their "great city" will accept the daunting reality that even greatness can go bankrupt.
Two recent essays pin each end of the "urban exodus" spectrum.
James Altucher's sensationalized
NYC Is Dead Forever, Here's Why focuses on the technological improvements in bandwidth that
enable digital-economy types to work from anywhere, and the destabilizing threat of rising crime.
In his telling, both will drive an accelerating urban exodus over the long-term,.
Jerry Seinfeld's sharp rebuttal,
So You Think New York Is 'Dead', focuses on the inherent greatness of NYC and other global
metropolises based on their unique concentration of wealth, arts, creativity, entertainment,
business, diversity, culture, signature neighborhoods, etc.
The core issue neither writer addresses is the financial viability of high-cost, high-tax urban
centers.
It's telling that Seinfeld's residency in Manhattan began in the summer of 1976, shortly after
the federal government provided loans to save the city from defaulting on its debts and declaring
bankruptcy.
In other words, Seinfeld arrived at the very start of New York's fiscal rebuilding, though its
social decline would continue for another few years (the 1977 blackout and looting, etc.).
Fiscal conservative Ed Koch was elected mayor in 1977 and by 1978, the city had paid off its
short-term debt.
This return to solvency laid the foundation for the eventual revival that attracted capital,
talent and hundreds of thousands of new residents, replacing the 1 million+ residents who had
moved to the suburbs in the tumultuous 1960s and 70s.
This urban exodus had led to urban decay which had generated a self-reinforcing feedback: the
greater the decline in livability, the more people who moved out, which then reduced commerce
and taxes, further exacerbating urban decay, and so on.
As I explained in
How Extremes Become More Extreme, these feedback loops are one way that Extremes Become
More Extreme until a tipping point / phase change is reached and livability and solvency
both collapse.
The other dynamic I discuss is the Pareto Distribution, the 80/20 rule which can be distilled
to 64/4 (80% of 80% is 64%, 20% of 20% is 4%). Once the vital 4% act, they exert outsized
influence on the 64%, far out of proportion to their numbers.
Thus the expanding criminality of the 4% criminal class can dramatically change perceptions
of safety and security of the 64%.
Telling people who no longer feel safe in the city that crime only went up 10% will not change
their minds.
If 20% of the businesses in a district close for good, the district might retain enough of
a concentration of commerce to draw customers.
But once the number of businesses plummets below a critical threshold, the survival of the
remaining enterprises becomes doubtful as the customer base drops below the level needed
to sustain the remaining businesses.
As I have repeatedly stressed, the surviving businesses are burdened by high fixed costs,
none of which have declined even as commerce collapsed.
Again, you cannot persuade people who no longer feel that shopping is safe and fun to get
out there and spend, spend, spend like they did a year ago.
Neither Altucher nor Seinfeld mention the macro-issues of demographics and the broader economy.
Despite soaring inflation and a roller-coaster stock market, jobs were plentiful in the 1970s,
partly because the Baby Boomers were entering the market for goods and services and partly
due to low costs for employers.
As late as the mid-1980s, it only cost me $50/month (one day's pay for a moderate-wage worker)
to provide good healthcare insurance for a single, young worker. Try buying a month of good
healthcare insurance today for one day's moderate-wage pay.
Not only were rents much cheaper (measured by the number of hours of work needed to pay rent),
there were "squats" where the rent was zero, and a variety of cheap "slum" dwelling options.
These options have mostly disappeared from the housing inventory, so it now takes enormous
sacrifices to live in a "great city".
Compare these positive demographics and cost structure then to the present. Not only are jobs
no longer plentiful, many of the Millennials who flocked to a "great city" for jobs and the
amenities can no longer afford to live there.
Many found jobs in the dining-out and retail sectors that have been devastated, and they only
survived financially by sharing flats with multiple roommates.
Costs such as healthcare insurance and housing are "sticky:" insurers, landlords, etc. are
reluctant to cut prices for fear that cost reductions may become permanent, hurting their
profitability.
These high costs are also endangering all the cultural institutions and commercial life that
attracted people to the "great cities." I doubt that every symphony, opera company, museum,
music venue, etc. will survive the downturn, due to their incredibly high fixed costs of operation.
As I've noted before, the patrons who are financially able to support these costly institutions
are older and wealthier, and have the most to lose if they feel their basic security is no
longer assured. They're the first to join the exodus to safer, less risky homes elsewhere.
Yes, they'll miss all the amenities, but not enough to make them stay.
I've also stressed the absolute necessity for any entity to be financially viable. If the
entity isn't viable in terms of income covering all expenses, it dissolves regardless of its
greatness.
Seinfeld is on solid ground arguing that great cities will never go away, as their benefits
are simply too compelling. On the other hand, goats were grazing in Rome's Forum, a few decades
after the Western Empire collapsed.
What collapsed wasn't just Imperial authority; the city could no longer afford all the
free bread and circuses which fed and amused much of its vast populace, not could it defend /
maintain the long trade routes that fueled commerce or the political structure that secured
the wealth of its nobility.
Cities are not cheap to operate, and they must continually attract workers and capital /
wealth which can both be taxed at a high rate. They also need a high volume of commerce
that can be taxed.
Most employers are facing a profound reset that will very likely require permanent cost-cutting
to maintain profits, and remote work is very cost-effective, as commuting and office space
are both unnecessary expenses that can be eliminated.
In terms of financial viability, much of the activity that generated taxes for "great cities"
is gone for good: downtown concentrations of tens of thousands of workers that supported
hundreds of small businesses, commercial landlords paying high property taxes, and so on.
The question nobody seems to be asking is: are cities no longer financially viable, given the
enormous cost of living, the high taxes needed to run the city, and the strong economic and
demographic headwinds?
What kind of city is possible if half the small businesses close and tax revenues fall by 50%?
What effect will those massive changes have on the livability of the city and its most
compelling attractions? How will the city provide services on half the revenues?
The worst-case scenario is only those who can't afford to leave will be left.
Unless great sacrifices are made by those remaining, that's not a recipe for financial viability,
it's a recipe for goats grazing in the Forum.
The best-case scenario is those who love their "great city" will accept the daunting reality
that even greatness can go bankrupt, and that the city will have to adapt in new and wrenching
ways to remain financially viable as tax revenues decline and some percentage of the wealthiest
taxpaying residents have left or will leave.
It's not just the urban exodus that's the challenge--it's who's in each successive wave of the
exodus. If the wealthy, the entrepreneurs and the displaced small business owners leave in
the first wave, the adaptation will have to be rapid and profound, as the modest, incremental
reforms that typify the past 75 years will not be enough to be consequential.
Of related interest:
Dear Jerry and James: You’re Both Wrong About New York (9/11/20)
My new book is available! A Hacker's Teleology: Sharing the Wealth of Our Shrinking Planet 20% and 15% discounts end September 30 (Kindle $7, print $17)
Read excerpts of the book for free (PDF).
The Story Behind the Book and the Introduction.
Recent Podcasts:
AxisOfEasy Salon #23: Lords of the Algos (1 hr)
My COVID-19 Pandemic Posts
My recent books:
A Hacker's Teleology: Sharing the Wealth of Our Shrinking Planet (Kindle $8.95, print $20, audiobook coming soon) Read the first section for free (PDF).
Will You Be Richer or Poorer?: Profit, Power, and AI in a Traumatized World
(Kindle $5, print $10, audiobook)
Read the first section for free (PDF).
Pathfinding our Destiny: Preventing the Final Fall of Our Democratic Republic ($5 (Kindle), $10 (print), ( audiobook): Read the first section for free (PDF).
The Adventures of the Consulting Philosopher: The Disappearance of Drake $1.29 (Kindle), $8.95 (print); read the first chapters for free (PDF)
Money and Work Unchained $6.95 (Kindle), $15 (print)
Read the first section for free (PDF).
If you found value in this content, please join me in seeking solutions by
becoming
a $1/month patron of my work via patreon.com.
NOTE: Contributions/subscriptions are acknowledged in the order received. Your name and email remain confidential and will not be given to any other individual, company or agency.
Thank you, Tristan ($5/month), for your splendidly generous pledge to this site -- I am greatly honored by your support and readership. |
Thank you, Michael W. ($5/month), for your superbly generous pledge to this site -- I am greatly honored by your support and readership. |